The agricultural relations were significantly altered as a result of the rise of feudalism. initially, the king was to grant land to the cultivator, but now the cultivator had to be granted land through a intermediary, which is referred in the law books of gupta and post gupta period as swamin. The land was first given to the cultivator, who then on occasion gave it to the sub cultivator. These formed societies may be broken down into a number of different categories of current events, which increases our level of expertise. The wealthier peasants were known as mahattar, while the less wealthy peasants were called kutumbin. Peasants themselves were separated into these two classes. Therefore, the divide of varna and caste was given an additional dimension by the addition of land. Land ownership rights also went through certain shifts as a result of the new arrangement. The community ownership of land is referenced in several ancient Indian literature. According to a later Vedic scripture called aiterya-brahamana, the earth voiced its disapproval of the actions of Visvakarman Bhauvana when he gave land to the priests as payment for the sacrifices they performed. This suggests that during ancient times, land could not be transferred without the authorization of the clan. The principle that what is regarded to be a livelihood (yoga kshema) cannot be split was established by Gautama, another lawgiver who lived after the Vedic period. This would certainly include land, which, according to this theory, could not be parceled up between the members of the family. Nevertheless, things were different throughout subsequent time periods. Both the mitaksara and the madanaparijata made the argument that the brahamana sons had the ability to split the landed property among themselves. In the eleventh through thirteenth century, yet later law writers explicitly legislated for the distribution of land. Peasants were only required to pay the monarch a tax on their output while the king was in power. However, the peasant was not required to pay anything for other items such as meadows, woods, or ponds. It was also possible for him to expand his farming operations into the arid, uncultivated territory. This suggested that the community of the hamlet had some kind of right over these issues. However, the beneficiary of some broad knowledge grants, notably those made by Pratihara rulers, was given the authority to exercise these privileges. In addition, a few of these gifts contained the ability to farm the land or have it cultivated for them. Notwithstanding the fact that this is not explicitly stated in the land grants, this has been construed as a right to eviction. All of these things point to the community of the village losing some of its common rights and putting those rights in the hands of an intermediary. During the middle ages, there was an increase in the use of visti, also known as forced labor, which was enforced on the peasants as a whole. On the other hand, in contrast to Europe, peasants in China were not typically compelled to work in the fields owned by their masters. Instead, forced labor was utilized for the construction of roads, palaces, and forts, as well as to assist in transporting the royal army and officials throughout the countryside. Local requirements were met locally, therefore there was no room for output on the market. This was one of the defining characteristics of the feudal economic system. This is the framework in which one should see the emergence of an economically self-sufficient hamlet. There are allusions to villages populated by craftsmen in previous eras; but, during the time of the Palas and Pratiharas, the population of villages consisted of brahamans, farmers, merchants, artisans, and chandalas, among other occupations. for the upkeep of the self sufficient economy it was necessary that all sections of primary producers should live in the village. There is a contradiction between the time and the expansion of Indian feudalism. during the period from 750 a.d. to about 1200 a.d., there had been a decline in trade commerce as can be inferred from the diminished use of coins. As a result of the decline in trade, artisans were forced to leave the cities and migrate to the villages, where they could find work, albeit at a subsistence level, allowing for the growth of an economically self-sufficient village economy. This has been cited as one of the reasons for the growth of an economically self-sufficient village economy. This self sufficient economy sustained itself for centuries and was not affected by the muslim rule of the country, as these rulers, despite being opposed to brahmans and polytheism, were not inclined to disturb the existing mode of production. This economy was not affected by the muslim rule of the country because it was self sufficient.